
Politicians and the media love emotionally charged words that add drama to otherwise dry policy debates.
Stock markets “crash” when they fall a few percent, health systems are “broken” when wait times are too long, a shortage of houses becomes a “crisis”, spending gets “slashed” and interest rates “hiked”.
The most powerful, though, are technical terms that carry emotional weight, as seen in the fierce election debate about whether or not New Zealand was in a “recession”.
Today, the contentious word might be “austerity”. That was the accusation levelled against Finance Minister Nicola Willis after she announced a $1.1 billion spending reduction aimed at keeping the Crown on course for a 2029 surplus.
Green Party co-leader Chlöe Swarbrick said this was “ushering in a new era of austerity” and the Public Service Association said it was a “recipe for austerity, which history tells us does not work”.
But what exactly is austerity? And does history show it doesn’t work?
Dictionary dialectics
Austerity is most broadly defined as any set of policies aimed at reducing government budget deficits through some combination of spending cuts or tax increases.
When defined by its critics, austerity usually refers to sharp government spending cuts that stifle economic growth, exacerbate poverty, and lead to even more cuts in the future.
It brings to mind the United Kingdom’s sluggish recovery after the 2008 Global Financial Crisis and the painful economic struggles in Greece following its debt crisis.
Willis and her colleagues want to avoid this association and argue the Government’s fiscal approach is a garden-variety ‘fiscal consolidation’, rather than austerity.
It’s a neutral, technical term that avoids the emotional baggage but essentially means the same thing. It’s not unlike the word ‘recession’, which evokes strong feelings despite having a somewhat softer definition.
(A stockbroker recently told me they advised clients to separate themselves from the macro story and ask, am I personally in a recession or not? That’s for another day, though.)
Grant Robertson once argued that the Crown should spend at least 30% of GDP and that anything less amounts to austerity. New Zealand remains well north of that threshold, with almost 34% forecast in 2025 and only falling to 31.5% in 2029.
Some argue high spending and ongoing deficits prove the Government isn’t doing austerity—but that’s incorrect. Austerity isn’t about having low spending, it's about cutting back from too-high levels.
Austerity has been made famous for its failures but has had some success as well.
Good cop, bad cop
In 1990, Canada proposed freezing federal payments, cutting business grants, capping military spending, and selling its state-owned oil company to reduce the budget deficit from US$25.3 billion to US$8.3 billion over five years.
The New York Times reported the story under the headline "Canada Presents Austerity Budget," and by 2000, the country had reduced its structural deficit by 6% of GDP and was running a surplus.
This is often cited as an example of successful austerity. Canada’s economy continued to grow despite spending cuts and a looming debt crisis was avoided.
It's a stark contrast to Greece, which had austerity measures imposed on it by the IMF and European lenders as part of a debt-crisis bailout. The country’s economy almost collapsed and debt-to-GDP ratios worsened — the IMF itself later admitted austerity was a mistake.
So, why does austerity fiscal consolidation work in some cases, but fail in others? Most researchers say it comes down to policy design and economic context.
There are a few basic rules for protecting economic growth while reducing deficits.
First, consolidation should happen when the local and global economy is strong or on an upswing. Output losses are larger during downturns because demand is already weak. 2025 might have been a good year for it, if it weren’t for Trump’s trade war.
Second, it’s better to rely on spending cuts than tax increases. International studies show tax hikes tend to have higher fiscal multipliers, meaning they drag more on economic growth. Multipliers vary, but the Treasury has found similar patterns in New Zealand.
Third, it should be gradual and avoid cutting critical services or productive investments that support long-term growth. The IMF now warns governments to resist the temptation to cut infrastructure, education, or health spending, as these can do lasting damage.
And finally, consolidation should be paired with supply-side reforms (and hopefully lower interest rates) that make it easier for the private sector to quickly pick up the economic slack left by government retreat.
Steady as she goes
Willis’ fiscal consolidation policies (we won’t call it austerity since it’s such a politically-loaded term) meets most of these orthodox criteria.
Critics argue more money should be spent on critical services and infrastructure but it’s a matter of degree, not direction. Taxes will only rise by 1% of GDP over the forecast period.
The spending cuts are gradual: Core Crown expenses will fall less than 3% as a percentage of GDP over the next four or so years, and the OBEGALx deficit will reduce from 3% to zero.
Ministers are also working on a wide range of pro-growth policy reforms, mostly in the form of deregulation. They may or may not benefit society but are generally good for growth
The real question is whether Willis is making a mistake by accelerating spending cuts in response to a weaker outlook, risking a repeat of failed austerity where cuts drive GDP lower in a vicious cycle.
She had previously suggested the Coalition would stick to its fiscal path and not overreact to forecast changes either way. Labour ran procyclical policy by increasing spending with extra revenue; National now risks repeating this mistake in reverse.
The broad strokes of Willis’ fiscal policy are roughly what experts recommend to reduce a deficit, but whether she is moving too soon or too fast remains up for debate.
12 Comments
Where do I start with this?
Shall we discuss how Canada 'reduced its structural deficit by 6% of GDP and was running a surplus' because, errrm, they exported hundreds of billions of dollars of natural gas and oil at high prices during that decade?
Or, shall we test ourselves against those 'four conditions'...
- local and global economy is strong or on an upswing
Fail.
- it’s better to rely on spending cuts than tax increases... tax hikes tend to have higher fiscal multipliers, meaning they drag more on economic growth [Hello! Not all taxes are created equally - taxing capital gains or earnings over $1m per year vs taxing people who work for a living will have totally different impacts on aggregate demand]
Fail.
- Cutting infrastructure, education, or health spending, as these can do lasting damage.'
Fail.
- Consolidation should be paired with supply-side reforms (and hopefully lower interest rates) that make it easier for the private sector to quickly pick up the economic slack left by government retreat.
Fail. Business private sector is not investing... because Govt investment crowds in private investment (stop listening to lunatic economists!)
Now, what about Govt spending being at 'too high levels'. What does that mean? Are we saying that Govt is having to spend billions more because the cost of living, and housing costs in particular, have reached such a crazy level relative to wages that Govt is having to tax more to redistribute more to people so that they can eat? Is that spending 'too high'? Or, does it perhaps suggest that our economy is out of balance?
Finally, but perhaps most importantly, we need to remember that current account deficits with the rest of the world are basically equivalent to Governments running a surplus (dragging money out of the economy). So, if our current account deficit is $25bn per year, and Govt deficit spending is $16bn per year, the net impact is minus $8bn. Increases in private sector debt need to offset this drain on our economy and then some to enable rich folks to save up. Sadly, this ain't happening. That's why the economy is on its ass.
Absolutely nailed it Jonny. A government (public sector surplus) = a private sector deficit. This is something most economists in NZ and everywhere else don't understand. In a fiat currency monetary system a deficit on the public sector balance sheet is a surplus in the private sector - i.e. the government is creating more new money through spending then it removes and destroys through taxation. Leaving money in the private sector for savings and surplus.
Tax receipts are not used to pay for government services - the government creates new money every time it spends and uses taxation to remove money from the economy to prevent inflation.
The really important point to understand about a fiat currency monetary system is taxes do not pay for government spending. Government spending has to happen first and is done by creating money out of thin air. Only after the money has been created and spent, can it then be taxed and saved as bonds.
As highlighted by the single offered example of a country that ran a surplus - Canada - exports also create new money and can be used to achieve surplus without reducing the money supply. However, relying completely on export based surplus has risks over the long term if trade conditions change suddenly.
If sensible government spending is called "austerity" then I am all for it.
The credit card analogy applies. Living on the card makes you happy, but only for a while.
Same with government overshoot. It's just a sneaky way to divert real physical resource, (thanks PDK) while pretending it isn't extracted from elsewhere. There is always a cost somewhere and maybe later.
Diverting resources to the public good? More doctors, nurses, teachers, less people dreaming up new ways to sell us SUVs? Sign me up.
KH - your comment highlights a broadly held misconception about government spending and debt. Government spending is intrinsically linked to its revenue. Typically governments that cut spending during a downturn will shrink the economy and increase overall government debt levels because the tax take falls off. This happens even as the operating deficit is reduced.
The equivalent for a house hold would be to cut spending but also decide to reduce income at the same time - the outcome is no real improvement in the overall financial position.
My perception is not a lot of sensible govt spending under Labour.
Housing NZ let loose and buying up land and building architecturally bespoke over the top houses, apartments with no regard to the cost. Refurbishing old state houses on sections sizes where it would make sense to build more accommodation that just fixing existing. Better use of land. I have two examples in New Plymouth. Wouldn't surprise me if this was not repeated elsewhere. I'm convinced without proof that Housing NZ has many admin types and managers who dropped out of a tree when shaken. I'm sure there are a very few who are quite capable but get smothered by the dross.
Ferries. This is likely to bite even the coalition in the bum as Labour was quite far down the track. Poorly drawn up contracts has a big part to play.
Dunedin hospital. Not thought through, poor project management and changes in scope. A contractors dream. Load up the bucks.
My impression of Labour. How much do you want we'll sign the cheque.
These are great examples of the point I was making - if the government spends less on infrastructure and the companies they contract employ less people to do the work and the suppliers supplying the builders sell less inventory .... who is losing out? Is that a good thing for the NZ economy? Where do all those contractors and builders spend the money the government gives them? Does it dissappear into some magic hole in the Beehive or is it spent directly into the private sector of the NZ economy?
The other thing to consider is the value of assets - Kaianga Ora's portfolio is solid, representing high-quality homes predominantly used to support disabled individuals and families with disabled children. The quality of the homes is reflected in their value and their long term expected life cycle. By the end of 2023 Kaianga Ora was building 6000 new homes per year employing thousands of builders, tradies and laborers - all tax paying NZ consumers. That is a lead by example government organization that was building and retaining productive capacity and crowding-in investment into the sector generally.
What's more Kianga Ora was self funding and able obtain loans for it's projects based on assets and income - so no tax-payer money involved. It was an incredible example of a successful and highly productive SOE.
All of what you say is admirable but how you get there is also very important. "highly productive SOE" that's a tall order. I still feel "How much do you want we'll sign the cheque." is applicable to Labour. Even an SOE will steer themselves to wards the ruling govt of the day.
Housing NZ is not an SOE, unless of course it became one after Oct2020 and this website has not been updated since then. https://www.dpmc.govt.nz/cabinet/portfolios/state-owned-enterprises
"The Coalition Government was elected to crack down on spending and get the Crown accounts back into balance"
Were they?...I'd suggest the Government were elected because they wernt Labour and the reason(s) for the desire for change had little to do with crown deficit...as evidenced by the opposition to a range of spending decisions across the board.
An article full of (incorrect) assertions it would seem.
Dan is constrained to making assumptions which fit a pre-written nanrrative.
That's a lot of things, but it isn't journalism.
And it's going to get worse as the gap (between physical truth and economics rhetoric) widens.
The historic economic data provides scant evidence or examples of extended government surplus (including temporary trade surplus) - it is just not economically feasible or desirable in a fiat currency monetary system.
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.